All the recent commotion over the agency model vs the wholesale model in ebook retailing reminded me of something: my very first pocket calculator. I got my first full-time job in September of 1974, and whereas fixing Xerox machines wasn’t riches, it paid me more than washing dishes at the local hospital. In short order I got my first credit card, my first new car, and a number of other things that had been waiting for my wallet to fatten up a little.
One of these was a pocket calculator. The device itself has been gone for decades, but I’m pretty sure it was a TI SR-50, with an SRP of $149.95. I shopped around for the best price, since $150 was a lot of money back then. However, everybody who sold the SR-50 was selling it for $149.95. I bought it at a camera store downtown, and only a little research told me that it was covered under the Fair Trade laws, meaning that all retailers sold it for the same price, set by the manufacturer. I grumbled a little, but wow! I had a calculator! I gave it no further thought.
Between 1931 and 1975, a significant chunk of retailing in the United States was basically on the agency model. Books, cameras, appliances, some foods, wine and liquors, and certain other things were sold for the price the manufacturer chose. This is one reason prices were often printed right on the goods. Retailer margins were open to discussion, but in a lot of industries, the margin was 40% or pretty close to it. The Fair Trade laws were enacted during the Depression to protect local one-off retailers from being driven out of business by much larger chain stores, during a time of reduced demand and thin profits. How well this worked is disputed, but by 1975 the laws had become so unpopular with the public and so difficult to enforce that they were repealed by an act of Congress.
I grant that Fair Trade was not a clear win for the little guys. Some of my readings suggest that the Fair Trade laws accelerated the dominance of retail chains because chain retailers could build bigger stores and shelve a greater variety of goods, even if their prices were the same as prices in smaller, one-off stores. House brands were invented largely to evade the Fair Trade laws, since the retailer was considered the manufacturer for legal purposes and could set prices in stores as desired. This gave another advantage to large chains, since only large chains had the resources to establish house brands.
Fair Trade retailing as I understand it rested on two big assumptions:
- Manufacturers compete on price.
- Retailers compete on things like customer service and selection.
Shazam! Those are the same two assumptions underlying the agency model in publishing, and I don’t think it matters whether we’re talking print or digital. So I think it’s fair to look at what happened after 1975, when Fair Trade went away:
- Discounting allowed consumer prices to go down.
- Both the chains as a whole and individual chain retail stores got bigger.
- Smaller, independent stores vanished in droves.
- Small retailing became specialty retailing. This was certainly true of bookstores. Of the two bookstores I could easily reach on my bike in the 1960s, one became a card shop that carried a few books, and the other became a specialty bookstore carrying Christian/Catholic books only.
- Small retailers dealing in used goods hung on longer–think used bookstores and used record stores. The Doctrine of First Sale allowed used goods retailers to set their own prices even on Fair Trade goods.
- Manufacturer consolidation went into high gear. One reason, I think, was monopsony, which is the power big retailers have to dictate prices to suppliers. Smaller manufacturers who could not meet retailer price expectations merged with larger manufacturers, became importers, or went under.
In the ebook publishing/retailing world, #5 does not apply, as there’s no unambiguously legal used market. Most of the other consequences in the list above are things that I predict an agency model would work against:
- Retail prices will rise–though perhaps not as much as some fear.
- It will be easier to mount and maintain a new online retailer against competition by enormous retailers like Amazon.
- Given the above, with the consequence of more players in the retail market, monopsonistic pressures on cover prices will be greatly reduced.
- Absent Amazon’s monopsony, smaller publishers have a better chance of competing with much larger publishers, given small publishers’ advantages of lower fixed costs vs larger publishers.
- The presence of a larger number of smaller publishers will keep downward pressure on prices, since that’s their primary way to compete. Macmillan has to keep ebook prices up to protect its print hardcover line. Ten thousand small ebook publishers have no hardcover lines to protect. $10? No problem. $5? The new $10. Even within the agency model, small press will train consumers to expect ebooks to sell for $10 or less.
There’s another consequence that I don’t think has any precedent in the Fair Trade phenomenon: Larger numbers of retailers and publishers will reduce the power of very large retailers or publishers to “silo” the business with proprietary file standards and DRM.
There are problems with such an agency-based business model (and wildcards; Pottermore, anybody?) but overall I think those problems are more solvable than the collapse of book retailing into Amazon, Amazon, and more Amazon. So my vote goes with agency retailing. I’ve just told you why. (Polite) discussion always welcome.
See http://jakonrath.blogspot.com/
and
http://aprillhamilton.blogspot.com/2012/04/amazon-vs-apple-and-agency-5-lets-get.html
for opposing points of view
Sorry it took so long to get to this; I’ve had other things on my mind the last few days.
I appreciate the pointers, but I’ll stick to my endorsement of agency pricing. Konrath’s post is borderline apoplectic, and an excellent example of how anger clouds the mind. I still can’t quite figure what he’s getting at, and I’ve read it three times.
April Hamilton’s post is more sensible, but she’s ducking the issue of selling ebooks (or anything else) below cost, and what effect that has on the retail channel. Amazon can do that because they’re huge and well capitalized. Smaller online stores cannot. Agency pricing is our best chance of keeping ebook retailing from collapsing into Amazon and nothing else.
The contention that wholesale pricing gives authors more money is bogus. Neither model is related strongly to author payments. Konrath’s position that author payments are the same whether a wholesaled book is sold at discount or not is true, and completely beside the point in the debate over wholesale vs. agency. Everything depends on the percentages and other terms in the contracts, and those are always subject to negotiation. A publisher using the agency model can pay an author 5% of 30%. It can also pay 40% of 30%. Everything depends on terms negotiated with the authors. Authors in some MM genres are getting much less than 12% of net, which is what most computer book authors were getting back when I was paying computer book authors. Both models are ways of splitting a pie. The guy who wins is the guy who holds the knife.
As the food chain shortens (inevitable as publishing jettisons the overhead required for print books) more money could conceivably flow to authors, irrespective of business model. Whether it does or not depends almost solely on supply and demand, and competition between publishers for talent.
The most favorable situation for authors is to have a huge number of small (weak) publishers selling through a huge number of small (weak) retailers. Anything that results in a handful of monster publishers selling through one gargantuan retailer will not be a good deal for authors. The wholesale model and (more to the point) loss-leader discounting is the best way I know to get to that very bad place.